By Andrew M. Mwenda
In Summary
Parliament and government should be kept out of business and allow the market through private investors, to deliver electricity.
Two weeks ago, an ad hoc committee of Parliament
recommended that government cancel its contract with Umeme for the
distribution of electricity in the country. The committee raises many
complaints against the concession agreement and Umeme’s performance; a
few correct, some legitimate, others completely wrong, many erroneous
and most of them ill-informed.
In fact, by relying on many erroneous and
ill-informed arguments to recommend an arbitrary cancellation of the
concession, the committee inadvertently demonstrates why it was vital
for Umeme to insist on the very provisions in the concession that
Parliament feels are unfair to the Ugandan people.
The background: When government decided to
unbundle Uganda Electricity Board (UEB) into three separate entities to
manage electricity generation, transmission and distribution, it hired
an international company called Fieldstone Private Capital Group Limited
to help handle the matter. After two years of work, government put out a
tender for generation and distribution concessions. Five companies
expressed interest and came to Uganda to do a due diligence on the
sector. After studying our political and regulatory framework, all of
them pulled out without submitting a bid.
The issues
What were the issues? They are largely of a political nature. Uganda had subsidised the electricity tariff for a very long time. The electricity tariff had remained unchanged from 1993 to 2002. The prevailing price then was far below the actual cost of generating, transmitting and distributing electricity; it’s value having been eroded by inflation and foreign exchange depreciation. The country had also ignored or condoned rampant power thefts. Thirdly many people who were in default were not being taken to task. Note: in Kenya the electricity tariff is subject to constant adjustment every year to both domestic inflation and foreign exchange depreciation.
What were the issues? They are largely of a political nature. Uganda had subsidised the electricity tariff for a very long time. The electricity tariff had remained unchanged from 1993 to 2002. The prevailing price then was far below the actual cost of generating, transmitting and distributing electricity; it’s value having been eroded by inflation and foreign exchange depreciation. The country had also ignored or condoned rampant power thefts. Thirdly many people who were in default were not being taken to task. Note: in Kenya the electricity tariff is subject to constant adjustment every year to both domestic inflation and foreign exchange depreciation.
Consequently, Ugandan electricity consumers took
it for granted that electricity was cheap and that its price could not
change. Secondly, there had grown and consolidated a culture of impunity
where thieves and defaulters could steal and/or refuse to pay and
remain untouched. These were causing high nontechnical losses in the
sector. To compound this, UEB had spent decades with little or no
investment in improving the distribution lines, transformers and meters.
This had led to high technical losses making the sector unattractive to
investors. UEB was a government parastatal and no one cared whether the
tariff covered the costs of electricity production.
The solution to this conundrum was doubled edged:
to reduce technical losses would demand heavy investment in upgrading
the power lines and transformers, meters and even more investment in
human resource.
If any private investor did this, they would have
to charge this cost through the tariff; second, to reduce nontechnical
losses required that the investor would have to ruthlessly clump down on
power thefts by riding homes and small businesses to apprehend illegal
connections, hire a security force to curb thefts of power lines,
transformers and tampering with meters and finally ruthlessly cut off
many defaulting customers off power to force them to pay. This operation
would destroy the image of any investor before his customers.
Besides, these measures had political
implications. Potential investors feared that the public would not
accept increases in the tariff because a culture of consuming cheap
electricity had penetrated the political consciousness of consumers.
Investors complained that the regulator did not have capacity to make
the independent decisions.
This is because the Electricity Regulatory
Authority (ERA) had once increased the tariff and government intervened
and suspended it. Indeed, if you look at the books of UEDCL, you will
find a back-to-back debt it owes generation and transmission companies
which has never been recovered. UEDCL could not collect money because
the minister stopped it from doing so for political reasons.
The Commonwealth Development Corporation (CDC) put
these issues in writing, rising issues of political risk, foreign
exchange risk and revenue collection risk. However, they said if these
issues were addressed, they could bid. The government decided to talk to
them. After the bidding, they formed a consortium with Eskom, one of
the other bidders. Both are parastatals, one owned by the British
government, another by the South African government. No private investor
was willing to risk their capital in such a tense political climate.
The negotiations between government on one hand
and CDC and Eskom on the other lasted three years. Government promised
to protect the investor from regulatory and political risks and the
concession was designed by escalating the penalties government would pay
in case of a breach.
This was the first distribution concession in
Africa. CDC and Eskom feared that if anyone attempted to increase the
tariff, especially at a steep rate, it would cause thefts, defaults and
illegal connections. So to concession made it clear that the government
could not increase the tariff for more than 10 per cent in any given
year and not more than 20 per cent in any three consecutive years.
Thus, although the public and Parliament accuse
Umeme of seeking to increase the tariff rapidly, Umeme has been against
it and this is enshrined in the concession agreement. In fact, rapid
increases in the tariff are a violation of the concession, which should
force Umeme to pull out. The question then was: if the tariff was going
to remain stable and change only by not more than 20 per cent every
three years, who was going to pay for the mismatch between the existing
tariff and actual cost of production, transmission and distribution? The
answer is government through the subsidy.
Even after government had agreed to these demands,
Umeme was reluctant to join and asked for an 18 months concession as a
trial run to see whether government would honour its word. They agreed
to invest a non-refundable $5 million (about Shs12.6 billion) in these
18 months. Five months to the end of that period, in March 2005, power
supply declined by 50 per cent due to low water levels in Lake Victoria.
This forced government to bring in thermal generators, a factor that
escalated the cost of electricity, thus making increasing the price of
subsidies.
Tariff increased
To avoid bankruptcy, government decided to increase the tariff by 22 per cent in March 2005, then 35 per cent in May 2006 and another 43 per cent in November 2006. Thus, in less than two years, government increased the tariff by 98 per cent contrary to the concession agreement. Again, Umeme had all the rights to terminate the concession. Government would have been forced to compensate them fully. Indeed they threatened to do exactly that, a factor that triggered negotiations with government.
To avoid bankruptcy, government decided to increase the tariff by 22 per cent in March 2005, then 35 per cent in May 2006 and another 43 per cent in November 2006. Thus, in less than two years, government increased the tariff by 98 per cent contrary to the concession agreement. Again, Umeme had all the rights to terminate the concession. Government would have been forced to compensate them fully. Indeed they threatened to do exactly that, a factor that triggered negotiations with government.
No comments :
Post a Comment